Current account
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
The current account is the difference between a nation's exports of goods and services and its imports of goods and services, if all financial transfers and investments and the like are ignored. A nation is said to have a current account deficit if it is importing more than it exports.
In economics, the current account is one of the two primary components of the balance of payments, the other being the capital account. It is the sum of the balance of trade (exports minus imports of goods and services), net factor income (such as interest and dividends) and net transfer payments (such as foreign aid).
The current account balance is one of two major metrics of the nature of a country's foreign trade (the other being the net capital outflow). A current account surplus increases a country's net foreign assets by the corresponding amount, and a current account deficit does the reverse. Both government and private payments are included in the calculation. It is called the current account because goods and services are generally consumed in the current period.[4]
Positive net sales abroad generally contributes to a current account surplus; negative net sales abroad generally contributes to a current account deficit. Because exports generate positive net sales, and because the trade balance is typically the largest component of the current account, a current account surplus is usually associated with positive net exports.
The net factor income or income account, a sub-account of the current account, is usually presented under the headings income payments as outflows, and income receipts as inflows. Income refers not only to the money received from investments made abroad (note: investments are recorded in the capital account but income from investments is recorded in the current account) but also to the money sent by individuals working abroad, known as remittances, to their families back home. If the income account is negative, the country is paying more than it is taking in interest, dividends, etc. For example, the United States' net income has been declining exponentially since it has allowed the dollar's price relative to other currencies to be determined by the market to a point where income payments and receipts are roughly equal.[citation needed] The difference between Canada's income payments and receipts have been declining exponentially as well since its central bank in 1998 began its strict policy not to intervene in the Canadian Dollar's foreign exchange.[5] The various subcategories in the income account are linked to specific respective subcategories in the capital account, as income is often composed of factor payments from the ownership of capital (assets) or the negative capital (debts) abroad. From the capital account, economists and central banks determine implied rates of return on the different types of capital. The United States, for example, gleans a substantially larger rate of return from foreign capital than foreigners do from owning United States capital.
In the traditional accounting of balance of payments, the current account equals the change in net foreign assets. A current account deficit implies a paralleled reduction of the net foreign assets.
Contents |
[edit] Reducing current account deficits
Action to reduce a substantial current account deficit usually involves increasing exports (goods coming out of a country and entering abroad countries) or decreasing imports (goods coming from a foreign country into a country). This is generally accomplished directly through import restrictions, quotas, or duties (though these may indirectly limit exports as well), or subsidizing exports. Influencing the exchange rate to make exports cheaper for foreign buyers will indirectly increase the balance of payments. This is primarily accomplished by devaluing the domestic currency. Adjusting government spending to favor domestic suppliers is also effective.
Less obvious but more effective methods to reduce a current account deficit include measures that increase domestic savings (or reduced domestic borrowing), including a reduction in borrowing by the national government.
[edit] The "Pitchford Thesis"
It should be noted that a current account deficit is not always a problem. The "Pitchford Thesis" states that a current account deficit does not matter if it is driven by the private sector. Some feel that this theory has held true for the Australian economy, which has had a persistent current account deficit, yet has experienced economic growth for the past 17 years (1991-2008). Others argue that Australia is accumulating a substantial foreign debt that could become problematic, especially if interest rates increase. A deficit in the current account also implies that the country is a net capital importer.
[edit] Interrelationships in the balance of payments
Absent changes in official reserves, the current account is the mirror image of the sum of the capital and financial accounts. One might then ask: Is the current account driven by the capital and financial accounts or is it vice versa? The traditional response is that the current account is the main causal factor, with capital and financial accounts simply reflecting financing of a deficit or investment of funds arising as a result of a surplus. However, more recently some observers have suggested that the opposite causal relationship may be important in some cases. In particular, it has controversially been suggested that the United States current account deficit is driven by the desire of international investors to acquire U.S. assets (See Ben Bernanke, William Poole links below). However, the main viewpoint undoubtedly remains that the causative factor is the current account and that the positive financial account reflects the need to finance the country's current account deficit.
[edit] The U.S.'s current account deficits
Since 1989, the U.S.'s current account deficits are increasingly larger, in 2006 reaching close to 7% of the U.S.'s GDP. This raises a lot of concerns in the academic and policy circles. New evidences, however, suggest that the U.S.'s current account deficits are being mitigated by positive valuation effects[6]. That is, the assets the U.S. holds overseas are gaining in value relative to the domestic assets held by foreign investors. The U.S. net foreign assets therefore is not deteriorating one to one with the current account deficits. The most recent experience has reversed this positive valuation effect, however, with the US net foreign asset position deteriorating by more than two trillion dollars in 2008.[1] This was due primarily to the relative under-performance of domestic ownership of foreign assets (largely foreign equities) to foreign ownership of domestic assets (largely US treasuries and bonds.)
[edit] See also
- Balance of payments
- Service sector
- U.S. public debt
- List of countries by current account balance
- Balance of trade
- FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data)
[edit] References
- ^ Current account balance, U.S. dollars, Billions from IMF World Economic Outlook Database, April 2008
- ^ Current account balance, Percent of GDP from IMF World Economic Outlook Database, April 2008
- ^ Current account balance and population from IMF World Economic Outlook Database, April 2008
- ^ Ecological Economics: Principles And Applications; Herman E. Daly, Joshua Farley; Island Press, 2003
- ^ Bank of Canada - Intervention in the Exchange Market
- ^ Current Account Sustainability and Relative Reliability
[edit] External links
- Are Trade Deficits a Drag on U.S. Economic Growth?
- Where Do U.S. Dollars Go When the United States Runs a Trade Deficit? from Dollars & Sense magazine
- CIA Fact Book of Account Rankings Worldwide
|