Tragedy of the anticommons
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
The tragedy of the anticommons is a neologism coined by Michael Heller to describe a coordination breakdown where the existence of numerous rights holders frustrates achieving a socially desirable outcome. The term mirrors the older term Tragedy of the Commons used to describe coordination breakdowns arising from insufficient rights holders. The concept provides a unifying framework for a range of coordination failures including patent thickets, submarine patents, nail houses, and more generally bureaucratic red tape. Overcoming these breakdowns can be difficult, often violent, but there are assorted means including eminent domain, Laches, patent pools or other licensing organizations.
The term originally appeared in Heller's 1998 article[1] and is the thesis of his 2008 book[2]. In a 1998 article[3] in Science, Heller, along with Rebecca Eisenberg, argue that biomedical research was one of several key areas where competing patent rights could actually prevent useful and affordable products from reaching the marketplace. Proponents of the theory claimed that too many property rights could lead to less innovation. The purported counter effect of the tragedy of the anticommons, the increased usefulness of a resource as the result of many individuals using it, has been dubbed the "comedy of the commons" by Carol M. Rose in a 1987 article that appeared in the University of Chicago Law Review. It is related to the concepts of network effects and non-rivalrous goods.
Contents |
[edit] Classic example
In Heller's 1998 Harvard Law Review article[1], he noted that after the fall of Communism, in many Eastern European cities there were a lot of open air kiosks, but also a lot of empty stores. Upon investigation, he concluded that because many different agencies and private parties had rights over the use of store space, it was difficult or even impossible for a startup retailer to successfully negotiate for the use of that space. Even though all the persons with ownership rights were losing money with the empty stores, and stores were in great demand, their competing interests got in the way of the effective use of space.
[edit] Patents
Patents often are cited as examples of the tragedy of the anticommons because a patent owner has exclusive rights over the use of the patented technology. If the creation of a certain product involves the use of many techniques and components patented by different people or different companies, then it can be very difficult to negotiate effectively with all the patent holders at once, and the result may be that one has to pay so many license fees that it becomes too expensive to create the desired product. Thus, a product that is in great demand may not be produced because costs associated with patents are too high.
Would-be manufacturers lose, the patent holders lose, and consumers in need who could have benefited from the technology lose. If medical technology is involved, people can lose their lives. And since the ones responsible for this (the patent holders) are also consumers, they lose twice. This phenomenon is a form of market failure. Paradoxically, when the patent holders act "rationally" to maximize their self-interest, they win nothing, everyone else loses, and they lose more than everyone else.
In most industries, a manufacturer will need to negotiate to use several patents in order to legally create a product. For example, a DVD player contains about a dozen devices that are patented by different companies. A single microchip can contain over 5,000 different patents. As such, no one can create a DVD player or a microchip unless every one of the patent holders agrees to license their patents. In many industries, patent holders either agree to cross-license their patents (i.e., you can use ours if we can use yours) or work out a common licensing agreement that makes products affordable. This generally means that for DVD players, computer components and other consumer electronics, the cost of licensing the patents is rarely much more than the manufacturing costs. For example, the license costs for the patents of a DVD player are about $20.00 (U.S.) for the cheapest models.
Due to the ease of patenting biological discoveries, it is likely that anyone working in biomedical research will have to use several patented procedures in order to create a marketable product. However, since those patents are short-lived and only a few patents result in a marketable product, those developing new treatments or processes often find that negotiating a licensing agreement with the patent holders is prohibitively expensive and will result in the product being unmarketable. In fact, a patent holder can often say that mere research is an infringing use, and demand a license fee, even though the chance of developing a marketable product is slim.
However, even one questionable patent can make marketing a product legally impossible. The recent dispute between Research In Motion and NTP, Inc. is over a single disputed wireless e-mail patent which is a key element of the BlackBerry. This resulted in an injunction that would have prevented the sale of the BlackBerry in the United States, but the injunction was stayed on appeal.
[edit] Copyrights
In the same way, competing use of copyrights can prevent a product from coming to the marketplace at a reasonable price, resulting in lost royalty income for the copyright holders. For example, WKRP in Cincinnati was one of the most popular syndicated sitcoms of all time, and many television shows from that era have been successfully released on DVD. However, for many years, WKRP has not been available on DVD. When it was a television program, an agreement was in place between television producers and music licensing organizations such as ASCAP and BMI wherein a standard licensing fee was paid for each song that was played on a television show. As such, the producers could determine how much money would be paid for their use of music clips and budget accordingly. However, there is no similar standard agreement for use of music on DVDs (which ASCAP and BMI do not control), and the producers are now faced with the prospect of negotiating individually with several dozen composers. The current owner of the show, 20th Century Fox, released a DVD of the show starting in the first half of 2007, using "soundalike" versions of music for which they could not obtain rights.
[edit] Eminent domain
In order to construct roads, railroads, and similar transportation arteries, eminent domain has long been considered necessary. Although the benefit to society from the transportation route may be substantial, without eminent domain every single one of the property owners along the way must agree in order for the route to be built; this provides the conditions for the tragedy of the anticommons, as even if hundreds agree, a single landowner could stop the road or railroad. The ability for one person to veto the construction drastically increases the transaction costs for such projects.
[edit] See also
[edit] References
- ^ a b Heller, Michael (January 1998). "The Tragedy of the Anticommons". Harvard Law Review.
- ^ Heller, Michael (2008). The Gridlock Economy: How Too Much Ownership Wrecks Markets, Stops Innovation, and Costs Lives. Basic Books. ISBN 978-0465029167. http://www.gridlockeconomy.com/.
- ^ Heller, M. A.; Eisenberg, R. (May 1998). "Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research". Science 280: 5364.
- Rose, Carol M. (1986) The Comedy of the Commons: Commerce, Custom and Inherently Public Property, 53 Univ. of Chi. L. Rev. 711 , reprinted as chapter 5 in: Rose, Carol M., Property and persuasion: Essays on the history, theory and rhetoric of ownership, Westview Press 1994
- Hickman, J. and Dolman, E.: "Resurrecting the Space Age: A State-Centered Commentary on the Outer Space Regime," Comparative Strategy, Vol. 21, No. 1, 2002.
- Depoorter, B., Parisi, F. and Schulz, N.: "Fragmentation in Property: Towards a General Model", Journal of Institutional and Theoretic Economics, Vol. 159, 594-613, 2003.
- Buchanan, James, and Yong Yoon. 2000. "Symmetric Tragedies: Commons and Anticommons", Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 43, No. 1.
[edit] External links
- The Tragedy of the Anticommons (Abstract, with link to complete paper)
- Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research (full text of article)
- The comedy of the commons, speech by Lawrence Lessig (Lawrence Lessig)
- Heller's talk in the Authors@Google series
- Website complementing gridlock economy: How Too Much Ownership Wrecks Markets, Stops Innovation, and Costs Lives