Herd behavior
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Herd behavior describes how individuals in a group can act together without planned direction. The term pertains to the behavior of animals in herds, flocks, and schools, and to human conduct during activities such as stock market bubbles and crashes, street demonstrations, sporting events, episodes of mob violence and even everyday decision making, judgment and opinion forming.
Contents |
[edit] Herd behavior in animals
A group of animals fleeing a predator shows the nature of herd behavior. In 1971, in the often cited article "Geometry For The Selfish Herd," evolutionary biologist W. D. Hamilton asserted that each individual group member reduces the danger to itself by moving as close as possible to the center of the fleeing group. Thus the herd appears to act as a unit in moving together, but its function emerges from the uncoordinated behavior of self-seeking individuals.[1]
[edit] Symmetry breaking in herding behavior
Asymmetric aggregation of animals under panic conditions has been observed in many species, including humans, mice, and ants. Theoretical models have demonstrated symmetry breaking similar to observations in empirical studies. For example when panicked individuals are confined to a room with two equal and equidistant exits, a majority will favor one exit while the minority will favor the other.
[edit] Possible mechanisms:
- Hamilton’s Selfish Herd Theory
- Byproduct of communication skill of social animal or runaway positive feedback
- Neighbor copying
[edit] Escape Panic Characteristics
- Individuals attempt to move faster than normal
- Interactions between individuals become physical
- Exits become arched and clogged
- Escape is slowed by fallen individuals serving as obstacles
- Individuals display a tendency towards mass or copied behavior
- Alternative or less used exits are overlooked[1]
[edit] Herd behavior in human societies
Psychological and economic research has identified herd behavior in humans to explain the phenomena of large numbers of people acting in the same way at the same time. The British surgeon Wilfred Trotter popularized the "herd behavior" phrase in his book, Instincts of the Herd in Peace and War (1914). In The Theory of the Leisure Class, Thorstein Veblen explained economic behavior in terms of social influences such as "emulation," where some members of a group mimic other members of higher status. In "The Metropolis and Mental Life" (1903), early sociologist George Simmel referred to the "impulse to sociability in man", and sought to describe "the forms of association by which a mere sum of separate individuals are made into a 'society' ". Other social scientists explored behaviors related to herding, such as Freud (crowd psychology), Carl Jung (collective unconscious), and Gustave Le Bon (the popular mind). Swarm theory observed in non-human societies is a related concept and is being explored as it occurs in human society.
[edit] Stock market bubbles
Large stock market trends often begin and end with periods of frenzied buying (bubbles) or selling (crashes). Many observers cite these episodes as clear examples of herding behavior that is irrational and driven by emotion -- greed in the bubbles, fear in the crashes. Individual investors join the crowd of others in a rush to get in or out of the market. [2]
Some followers of the technical analysis school of investing see the herding behavior of investors as an example of extreme market sentiment.[3] The academic study of behavioral finance has identified herding in the collective irrationality of investors, particularly the work of Robert Shiller,[4] and Nobel laureates Vernon Smith, Amos Tversky, and Daniel Kahneman.
Hey and Morone (2004) analysed a model of herd behavior in a market context. Their work is related to at least two important strands of literature. The first of these strands is that on herd behavior in a non-market context. The seminal references are Banerjee (1992) and Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer and Welch (1992), both of which showed that herd behavior may result from private information not publicly shared. More specifically, both of these papers showed that individuals, acting sequentially on the basis of private information and public knowledge about the behavior of others, may end up choosing the socially undesirable option. The second of the strands of literature motivating this paper is that of information aggregation in market contexts. A very early reference is the classic paper by Grossman and Stiglitz (1976) that showed that uninformed traders in a market context can become informed through the price in such a way that private information is aggregated correctly and efficiently. A summary of the progress of this strand of literature can be found in the paper by Plott (2000). Hey and Morone (2004) showed that it is possible to observe herd-type behavior in a market context. Their result is even more interesting since it refers to a market with a well-defined fundamental value. Even if herd behavior might only be observed rarely, this has important consequences for a whole range of real markets – most particularly foreign exchange markets.
[edit] Behavior in crowds
Crowds that gather on behalf of a grievance can involve herding behavior that turns violent, particularly when confronted by an opposing ethnic or racial group. The Los Angeles riots of 1992, New York Draft Riots and Tulsa Race Riot are notorious in U.S. history, but those episodes are dwarfed by the scale of violence and death during the Partition of India. Population exchanges between India and Pakistan brought millions of migrating Hindus and Muslims into proximity; the ensuing violence produced an estimated death toll of between 200,000 and one million. The idea of a "group mind" or "mob behavior" was put forward by the French social psychologists Gabriel Tarde and Gustave Le Bon.
Sporting events can also produce violent episodes of herd behavior. The most violent single riot in history may be the sixth-century Nika riots in Constantinople, precipitated by partisan factions attending the chariot races. The football hooliganism of the 1980s was a well-publicized, latter-day example of sports violence.
[edit] Everyday decision-making
Benign herding behaviors may be frequent in everyday decisions based on learning from the information of others, as when a person on the street decides which of two restaurants to dine in. Suppose that both look appealing, but both are empty because it is early evening; so at random, this person chooses restaurant A. Soon a couple walks down the same street in search of a place to eat. They see that restaurant A has customers while B is empty, and choose A on the assumption that having customers makes it the better choice. And so on with other passersby into the evening, with restaurant A doing more business that night than B. This phenomenon is also referred as an information cascade. [5] [6]
[edit] See also
- Anxiety
- Bandwagon effect
- Collective behavior
- Collective consciousness
- Collective effervescence
- Collective intelligence
- Crowd psychology
- Conformism
- Fear
- Flocking (behavior)
- Group behavior
- Groupthink
- Herd mentality
- Hive mind
- Informational cascade
- Mass hysteria
- Mean world syndrome
- Meme
- Mob rule
- Moral panic
- Propaganda
- Self-organization
- Sheeple
- Socionomics
- Spontaneous order
- Swarm intelligence
- Symmetry Breaking in Herding Behavior
- Team player
[edit] References
- ^ a b W. D. Hamilton (1971), "Geometry for the Selfish Herd," Journal of Theoretical Biology, Volume 31, Issue 2, pp. 295-311.
- ^ Markus K. Brunnermeier, Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information: Bubbles, Crashes, Technical Analysis, and Herding, Oxford University Press (2001).
- ^ Robert Prechter, The Wave Principle of Human Social Behavior, New Classics Library (1999), pp. 152-153.
- ^ Robert J. Shiller, Irrational Exuberance, Princeton University Press (2000), pp. 149-153.
- ^ Abhijit V. Banerjee, "A Simple Model of Herd Behavior," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 3, pp. 797-817.
- ^ Sushil Bikhchandani, David Hirshleifer, Ivo Welch. October 1992. "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades." Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No.5, pp. 992-1026.
- Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirshleifer, David, and Welch, Ivo. "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades." Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No.5, pp. 992-1026, 1992.
- Wilfred Trotter, The Instincts of the Herd in Peace and War, 1914.
- Brunnermeier, Markus Konrad. Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information : Bubbles, Crashes, Technical Analysis, and Herding. Oxford, UK ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2001.
- Rook, Laurens. "An Economic Psychological Approach to Herd Behavior." Journal of Economic Issues 40.1 (2006): 75-95.
- Hamilton, W D. Geometry for the Selfish Herd. Diss. Imperial College, 1970.
- Rook, Laurens. "An Economic Psychological Approach to Herd Behaviour." Journal of Economic Issues XL (2006): 75-95. Ebsco. Fall. Keyword: herd Behavior.
- Stanford, Craig B. "Avoiding Predators: Expectations and Evidence in Primate Antipredator Behaviour." International Journal of Primatology 23 (2001): 741-757. Ebsco. Fall. Keyword: Herd Behaviour.
- Ottaviani, Marco, and Peter Sorenson. "Herd Behavior and Investment: Comment." American Economic Review, Vol. 90, No. 3, 695-704. Jun., 2000.
- E. Altshuler., et. Al. Symmetry Breaking in Escaping Ants. The American Naturalist. 166:6. 2005.
[edit] Further reading
- Transmission of Information and Herd Behavior in Finance Irrationnalites en bourse... les simuler! les expliquer? (fr)
- Are You A Herd Follower or Leader? (Comic)