Social identity

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to: navigation, search

Social identity is a theory formed by Henri Tajfel and John Turner[1] to understand the psychological basis of intergroup discrimination. It is composed of four elements:

  • Categorization: We often put others (and ourselves) into categories. Labeling someone a Muslim, a Turk, a Gimp, or a soccer player are ways of saying other things about these people.
  • Identification: We also associate with certain groups (our ingroups), which serves to bolster our self-esteem.
  • Comparison: We compare our groups with other groups, seeing a favorable bias toward the group to which we belong.
  • Psychological Distinctiveness: We desire our identity to be both distinct from and positively compared with other groups[2].

As developed by Tajfel, social identity theory is a diffuse but interrelated group of social psychological theories concerned with when and why individuals identify with, and behave as part of, social groups, adopting shared attitudes to outsiders. It is also concerned with what difference it makes when encounters between individuals are perceived as encounters between group members. Social identity theory is thus concerned both with the psychological and sociological aspects of group behaviour.

Reacting against individualistic explanations of group behaviour (e.g. Floyd Allport) on one hand, and tendencies to reify the group on the other, Tajfel sought an account of group identity that held together both society and individual. Tajfel first sought to differentiate between those elements of self-identity derived from individual personality traits and interpersonal relationships (personal identity) and those elements derived from belonging to a particular group (social identity). Each individual is seen to have a repertoire of identities open to them (social and personal), each identity informing the individual of who he is and what this identity entails. Which of these many identities is most salient for an individual at any time will vary according to the social context. Tajfel then postulated that social behaviour exists on a spectrum from the purely interpersonal to the purely intergroup. Where personal identity is salient, the individual will relate to others in an interpersonal manner, dependent on their character traits and any personal relationship existing between the individuals. However, under certain conditions "social identity is more salient than personal identity in self-conception and that when this is the case behaviour is qualitatively different: it is group behaviour."

"Social identities... are associated with normative rights, obligations and sanctions which, within specific collectivities, form roles. The use of standardized markers, especially to do with the bodily attributes of age and gender, is fundamental in all societies, notwithstanding large cross-cultural variations which can be noted." by Giddens

In the sphere of economics, two separate papers by Akerlof and Kranton[3][4] incorporate social identity factor to principal-agent model. The main conclusion is that when the agents consider themselves insiders, they will maximize their identity utility by exerting the high effort level comparing with the prescription behavior. On the other hand, if they consider themselves outsiders, they will require a higher wage to compensate their lose for behavior difference with prescription behaviors. While this macro-economic theory deals exclusively with already well established categories of social identity, Laszlo Garai when applied the concept of social identity in the economic psychology[5] takes into consideration identities in statu nascendi[6]. This theory that is referred to the macro-processes based on a large-scale production later gets applied to the individual creativity's psychology: Garai derived it from the principal's and, resp., agent's identity elaboration.

Chen and Li[7] test the social identity effect in the lab using strategic method and find that when people are matched with ingroup members, they will be more likely to have “charity” concern[8] and less likely to have “envy” concern. Another experiment conducted by Oxoby[9] has the same results with Chen and Li in the aspect of positive reciprocity, but in the negative reciprocity, evidences from Oxoby show that people will be more likely to take revenge when they get negative reciprocity from in-group members in sequential games, which leaves it as an open question in both experimental economics and social identity theory.

[edit] References

  1. ^ Tajfel, Henri; Turner, John (1979). "An Integrative Theory of Intergroup Conflict". in Austin, William G.; Worchel, Stephen. The Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations. Monterey, CA: Brooks-Cole. pp. 94–109. ISBN 0818502789. OCLC 4194174. http://books.google.com/books?id=EzW6AAAACAAJ&dq=%22The+Social+Psychology+of+Intergroup+Relations%22. Retrieved on 2008-07-21. 
  2. ^ Taylor, Donald; Moghaddam, Fathali (1994-06-30). "Social Identity Theory". Theories of Intergroup Relations: International Social Psychological Perspectives (2nd ed.). Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers. pp. 80–1. ISBN 0275946355. OCLC 29319924. http://books.google.com/books?id=kBSZjkKSShMC&printsec=frontcover&dq=%22Theories+of+Intergroup+Relations%22&sig=ACfU3U3NPf0dlFE2OJM4Txv8U6ha8YlHgw. Retrieved on 2008-07-21. 
  3. ^ Akerlof, George A.; Kranton, Rachel E. (August 2000). "Economics and Identity". The Quarterly Journal of Economics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press) 115 (3): 715–53. doi:10.1162/003355300554881. OCLC 1763227. http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/003355300554881. Retrieved on 2008-07-21. 
  4. ^ Akerlof, George A.; Kranton, Rachel E. (Winter 2005). "Identity and the Economics of Organizations". Journal of Economic Perspectives (Nashville, TN: American Economic Association) 19 (1): 9–32. doi:10.1257/0895330053147930. OCLC 16474127. http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/aea/jep/2005/00000019/00000001/art00002. Retrieved on 2008-07-21. 
  5. ^ Garai, Laszlo: Identity Economics
  6. ^ Cf. e.g. Garai, Laszlo: The Bureaucratic State Governed by an Illegal Movement: Soviet-Type societies and Bolshevik-Type Parties. Political Psychology. 1991. 10:1. 165-179.
  7. ^ Chen, Yan; Li, Xian (Sherry) (2006-10-30). "Group Identity and Social Preferences". Working Paper. http://www.si.umich.edu/~yanchen/papers/identity_20061030.pdf. Retrieved on 2008-07-20. 
  8. ^ Charness, Gary; Rabin, Matthew (August 2002). "Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests". The Quarterly Journal of Economics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press) 117 (3): 817–69. doi:10.1162/003355302760193904. OCLC 1763227. http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/003355302760193904. Retrieved on 2008-07-21. 
  9. ^ Oxoby, Robert J.; McLeish, Kendra N. (January 2007). "Identity, Cooperation, and Punishment". Discussion Paper No. 2572. Institute for the Study of Labor. http://ideas.repec.org/p/iza/izadps/dp2572.html. Retrieved on 2008-07-20. 

[edit] External links

Personal tools